PUBLIC SECTOR PRODUCTION AND PRICE
A. Marginal Price
Principles
The principles of public company pricing has long
been a subject of discussion, and specific reference should be made to
traditions in France, dating back the work of the Ecole des Ponts et Chaussées
in the early nineteenth century (Ekelund, 1973). Much literature has argued in
favor of marginal cost pricing, an thet case forcibly put in a paper Hotelling
Hotelling klasikny found the price to be set at marginal cost, and that any
resulting deficit in reducing the cost of the industry, will be financed by a
lump-sum tax. This is to price the marginal cost must be seen as the first-best
argument.
As we have emphasized in previous Lectures, there is
a reason why there may be restrictions on the use of lump-sum taxes and why the
government may have to rely on taxation distortion (indeed, actually called by
Hotelling tax tends to finance the deficit has to be raised by way of
distorting - so for them the price of economic activity is not the same
marginal cost - there is no presumption that the optimal price in state
enterprises will require marginal cost pricing if desired distribution can not
be achieved by the bump.-sum means pieces may have used public sector as a tool
for this purpose.
B.Control on Public
Enterprises
Formal similarity between the issues of taxation and
public enterprise prices provide considerable insight, but failed to do justice
to the complexity of the questions that arise from the relationship between the
company and the state government, and before presenting our analysis should
comment briefly on some of the relevant issues.
On the central question is the nature of the
"directives" from the government to the "state", and the
degree of autonomy of the latter. There are different levels of autonomy. On
the one hand, the company can be run like a government department (as sometimes
happens with the Post Office), on the other hand, the company can become an
autonomous corporation like IBM or ICI, with the country receiving benefits as
the other shareholders (this true, for example, of certain joint ventures).
More common is the intermediate case, in which
public companies have independent management, but arranged by country of
destination and are subject to certain restrictions. Formal organizational
relationship may, however, are not perfectly reflect the level of autonomy. The
civil servants running the Post Office may have the freedom of action that the
head of satay steel companies, which may be directed to search for plans in
certain areas, to build some kind of plant. Etc.In the design of administrative
structures, the key role played by incentive information problems we have
mentioned on several occasions.
An interesting question raised is not that we have
room to explore here, and just assume that the structure is the nature of the
two following steps. First, the government set corporate objectives and
constraints. For example, he decided on the level of return on capital targets
to be achieved by the industry and the amount of state subsidy (if any).
Second, firms determine pricing policy so as to maximize the function of the
subject is the goal constraints. For example, given that the National
Electricity Corporation must make a profit of $ x, how should it determine the
price relative to domestic and industrial users? The nature of the efficiency
and equity of outcome depends on decisions made in the second stage.
With this kind of structure, there is no direct
relationship between public companies. National Electric Corporation does not
account for the impact of the policy on the National Coal Corporation. Such
interaction - that affect such things as transfer pricing - need to be
considered by the government lays down guidelines for each company, for
example, to allow for the fact that they can produce closely competing products
(eg, long-distance trains and air services).
Two-tier structure is one reason why it is parallel
with the literature on optimal taxation incomplete.In this case, there is a
problem one stage. If we apply the results of Ramsey directly at the individual
company level, we ignore the fact that the problem itself is the subject of
choice. Profit targets for different industries set by the government, and
consider interdependence. On the other hand, if we collapse problems in one
stage, and treat all public companies as a whole, we ignore the fact that the
design guidelines are an important feature of the decentralization of public
sector institutions.
C.MARGINAL COSTS
1.
Profit
The simplest situation is that of a single public
company, producing a quality product in the nal Z (in per capita terms), if it
is not competitive in the economy (in which per capita private output vector is
denoted by X). all individuals have identical utility function U (X, Z, L),
where L is the amount of labor supplied per person. Labor is taken as
numeraire. We are represented by a vector q of the product price by the private
sector and the public output price p. Production constraints assumed form
Ω
≡ F (X) + C (Z) - L = 0 (15-1)
There
are F (X) provides workforce needs in the private sector, and (Z) are in the
public sector. It is assumed that the convex production sets, conditions for
profit.
Π
≡ q. X - F (X) (15-2) (For example, the value of net output minus labor costs),
maximized necessary condition for which is that qi = Fi, where the latter shows
an instance of the Xi. assumed at this stage that there are constant returns to
scale in the private sector. So Π ≡ 0. Implications of pure profit we will
discuss later.
Public companies are assumed to determine the price,
p, to maximize social welfare, as measured by the indirect utility function of
the representative consumer, denoted by V (qp). companies limited by income
(per person)
pz
- C (Z) + T> Π0 (15-3)
where T indicates subsidized by the government and
Π0 profit targets. Assumed subsidy financed by lump-sum taxation, so that T
enters the indirect utility function. There are no other taxes are assumed at
this stage. The solution to the price problem can be seen by forming the
Lagrangian.
L
= V (qpT) + λ [PZ - C (Z) + T-Π0 (15-4)
First condition with respect to p can be written
using the properties of the indirect utility function (assuming constant
returns to scale in the private sector means that the change is only in the V
is that arising directly from p):
-
ΑZ + λ [Z + (p-C1) ∂ Z / ∂ p] (15-5)
where
α is the marginal utility of private pendapatan.Misalkan first that T is the
independent variable, so that the lump-sum taxation can be used to finance any
deficit. First condition with respect to T (using the fact that (provided ∂ V /
∂ T =-α) is that
-
Α + λ = 0 (15-6)
From
(15-5) it follows that (provided ∂ z / ∂ p ≠ 0) the conditions necessary for
optimal is that
p
= C1 (Z) (15-7)
price
equals marginal cost. This is an overview of the standard arguments for the
price it costs marjinal.Dimana no constraints on the use of T, and the company
has a profit target of effective, then the rule should be modified price. Let T
≤ 0, and the marginal cost price is not enough to allow the company to meet
(15-3). This situation is illustrated in Fig. 15-1, which target the profits to
be breaking even. At this level of output where price equals marginal cost, the
deficit shown by the hatched area. In other to meet profit targets, the company
had to reduce output to ZB, where price exceeds marginal cost. As illustrated
in the diagram, the instructions to the company to break even fully determine
its pricing policy. It sets a price above marginal cost to the extent necessary
to avoid a deficit.
In practice, public companies produce more than one
product, and it introduced a degree of That
the mark-ups over marginal so must conform to "the market will bear",
that is, inversely proportional to pasticity request. Against the position that
the price should oportional marginal cost, advanced by, among others, Frisch
(1939) and Allais (1948).
In other to consider the merits of the rival views,
we can modify the initial analysis, so the maximization problem is now
represented by the Lagrangian:
L = V (q, p1, p2, T) + λ [p1Z1 p2Z2 C + + (Z1, Z2) +
T - Π0] (15-8)
The
tax rate assumes that the lump-sum fixed. The first of these conditions with
respect to p1, p2, and prices are:
-ΑZ_1
+ λ [(p_1-C_1) (Z_1 ∂) / (∂ p_1) + (p_2-C_2) (Z_2 ∂) / (∂ p_1) + Z_1] = 0
(15-9)
-ΑZ_2
+ λ [(p_1-C_1) (Z_1 ∂) / (∂ p_2) + (p_2-C_2) (Z_2 ∂) / (∂ p_2) + Z_2] = 0
There
C1 denotes ∂ C / ∂ Z_1. Parallel to the Ramsey problem should be clear at this
point, if we write C1 ≡ p1-t1.
If we consider the special case in which the demands
are independent and there is no income effect, then, rearrange,
(P_1-C_1)
/ p_1 ((p_1-C_1) / p_1) = (λ-α) / λ
This results in Ramsey familiar, that
"tax" should inversely proportional to the elasticity of demand,
because it supports "what the market will bear" look rather than the
rule of proportionality Frisch-Allais. This, and other implications, brought
out by Boiteux (1956). Devinations level of marginal cost pricing depending on
budget constraints. If this is not binding (eg, because the lump-sum tax can be
used) λ = α and p1 = C1. At the other extreme, the approach takes advantage α,
and the right side (15-10) tend to unity. maximum, λ These results restrict
price-discriminating monopoly case, because marginal revenue equals marginal
cost implies
(P_1-C_1)
/ p_1 (ε_1 ^ d) = 1 (15-11)
D.Benefit in the Private Sector
Assumptions made so far do not allow for pure profit
in the private sector, which arise in the competitive case where there is a
decline back to the scale. We now consider the implications of the profits for
the price of a public company and its relation to the optimal tax formula.
There is no general loss in anger for untaxed (as in
the analysis to this point). But this is no longer true in which consumers
receive income benefits, because multiplying all producer prices by 5 implies
that the income gains are also multiplied by 5. The effect can be offset simply
by multiplying all consumer prices by 5. The assumption of good untaxed
inocouos not in this case. We can normalize the price of ore a manufacturer of
consumer prices.
Restrictions on commodity taxation is very important
then to be considered in conjunction with restrictions on the rate of tax on
pure profit. Suppose we set on the unity of the producer price (the work). The
advantage of the private sector (per capita)
Π = s X - F (X) (15-2 ')
It is assumed to be taxed at the rate t, so that the
lump-sum income received by a household is (1 - τ) Π (≡ I). Such taxes can be
quivalent to all consumer prices rising by a factor of 1 / (1 - τ), since the
demand function is homogeneous of degree zero in consumer prices and
The exhausting of pure profit that can be achieved
by a uniform tax on all goods (and labor). In what follows we assume that τ is
fixed, and that there is an untaxed goods, which is taken to be labor.
Individual budget limit then, the Z output of the public sector.
q X + Z = L p + (1 - τ) Π (15-12)
Combined with production constraints and (15-2 '),
this yields the budget constraint of the public sector (per capita):
p Z - C (Z) + (q-s) X + τ Π = 0 (15-13)
or
p Z - C (Z) + q X - F (X) - (1 - τ) Π = 0 (15-3 ')
Let us now consider the position of the public
sector as a whole to determine the price to be charged is liable to tax all
goods except labor (and no poll tax or subsidy). Maximization problem can then
be formulated in terms of the Lagrangian:
L = V (q, p1, p2, I) + λ [p Z - C (Z) + q X - F (X)
- (1 - τ) Π] (15-14)
Another
condition for the first-choice adala pk ∂ V / (∂ p_k) + ∂ V / ∂ ∂ II / (∂ p_k)
+ λ [+ Σ_j Z_k ▒ 〖(q_j-F_j) (X_j
∂) / (∂ p_k)〗 - (1-τ) (∂ Π) /
(∂ p_k)] (15-15)
Effect
on profit given by (from (15-2 '))
(∂
Π) / (∂ p_k) = Σ_j ▒ 〖(Σ_m
▒ 〖X_m
(S_m ∂) / (∂ X_j))〗〗
(S_j ∂) / (∂ p_k) (15-16)
All profits are returned to the government, so there
is no supply of entry consideration. In the case of private goods, where the
rate of tax on profits of less than 100 percent, the supply side must
diperhitungkan.Sebuah natural question at this point is why the government does
not impose a 100 percent tax profits. Previously, we provide some explanation
as to why lump-sum tax should not be the sole source of income. However, if the
tax advantages of non-distortionary, surely they should be set at 100 percent,
and thus the question which we have been concerned ceased to be relevant?
In practice, the government does not follow
this policy Henry George-like. Although the war some countries have imposed
additional 100 percent tax rate, they usually do not charge a regular 100
percent tax on profits and income from the fixed factor. The reason for this
will come back to the lack of information at the disposal of the government.
Most importantly, he found difficulty in distinguishing pure profit from the
return to capital, or the return to entrepreneurship. This is seen most clearly
in the case of unincorporated enterprises. If there is a 100 percent profit
tax, no company would ever declare profits will always distribute "pure
profit" as a reward to entrepreneurs.
SUPPLY
OF GOODS GENERAL PUBLIC PRIVATE
At first we need to make an important distinction,
between production and public provision. The two are often confused, even
though logically and in practice they are different. The government provides
for national defense, but a lot of the production of goods purchased for the
national defense is in the private sector. The government has, in many countries,
amonopoly mail service, but the cost for the use of the letter a little
differently than a private company. In Lecture previeus we deal with public
commodity produced, the following is related to the goods and services provided
freely, perhaps rationed amount, to all members of society.
Free provision of goods can be seen as a limiting
case of subsidies. namely, delivery of commodities to consumers at prices below
the cost of production. In this sense, the analysis of this lecture, and that
the price of the public sector, are aspects of the same subject. But there are
distinct features of the provision of public services which approach does not
capture and that is the focus of much of our discussion: the provision of
public services there is no need for monitoring the use, while any price,
positive or negative, the use must be recorded.
The issue of monitoring the use of the first to
introduce the relevant aspects of the characteristics of the goods or the
public should be given: it may be impossible, or very expensive, the cost for
the use of a particular commodity. In other words, it is not possible to
exclude non-contributors. This is basically a technical question, and depending
on the technology available.
In this view, the personal is at one extreme of the
spectrum, where one unit increase in consumption by Mr. X to reduce consumption
available to others by one unit, and pure public goods at the other extreme,
where the increase in consumption of Mr X cause no reduction for others. Polar
cases sometimes characterized in the following way.
X_i
^ h a h household consumption of commodity i. Then for personal items,
Σ_h
x_i ▒ 〖〗
^ h = x_i (16-1)
Where
Xi is aggregate supply. Conversely, for pure public goods,
X_i
^ h = x_i all h (16-2)
It may be noted that it is not responsible disposal
free of charge. For public goods, such as defense, this is probably not
unreasonable assumption, on the other hand, for items such as televisions, free
disposal is possible, and (16-2) should be replaced by
^
X_i x_i all h ≤ h (16-2 ')
Case intermediated rather difficult to characterize,
and various approaches have been proposed in the literature. One is to write
the consumption possibility frontier for the economy as well:
ᵡ
(x_i ^ 1, ..., ..., x_i ^ h, x_i) = 0 (16-2) with
(∂
ᵡ) / (∂ x_i ^ h) = 0 (for all h) for pure public goods,
(∂
ᵡ / ∂ x_i ^ h) / (∂ ᵡ / ∂ x_i ^ k) = 1 (for all h, k) for pure public goods
Table 16-2
Experimental evidence on willingness to pay
Costly
exclusion
|
Demand
irresponsive
|
Low
cost of individual supply
|
Distributional
arguments
|
|
?
|
?
|
?
|
?
|
|
National
defence
Roads
and bridges
TV
and radio
Education
Water
Police
|
Yes
Yes
Yes ?
Yes
|
Yes
Yes
|
Yes
Yes ?
Yes
Yes
|
Yes
Yes ?
Yes
|
Medical
care
Fire
protection
Legal system –
criminal case
– civil cases
Leverage and rubbish
National park
|
2.OPTIMUM EFFICIENCY SUPPLY PURE PUBLIC GOODS
In
this section we consider the optimal level of provision of good, pure single
public, consumed in quantity G by everyone. There are aggregate production
relationship:
F
(X, G) = 0 (16-5)
Where
X represents the vector production both personal number.
The government fully controlled economy is assumed
to choose the level of G, and the allocation of private Xh for household h (h =
1 where ....... H) to maximize individualistic social welfare function. If the
individual utility function Uh (Xh.G). then ma social welfare function is
written as follows
Ψ
U 1, ..., U h, ..., UH] (16-6) where Ψ is assumed to function, twice
differentiable concave to be increased in all the arguments. If we form the
Langrangean
=
Ψ - λF (X, G) (16-7) the first order condition (∂) / (∂ x_i ^ h) (X, G) = 0
(16-8a)
F
(X, G) = 0 (16-8b)
Conditions
(16-8a) gives the condition first-best welfare standards (equation marginal
rate of substitution and transformation). New conditions (16-8b).
Of
(16-8a) we can see that (ie, the left side is the same for all h). we can then
divide the hth term in the sum on the left side (16-8b) to give
This is a basic condition for the provision of
public goods optimal: the number of the marginal rate of substitution between
public goods (and some good private) should be equal to the marginal rate of
transformation (MRT ΣMRS =). There is a clear intuitive interpretation of this
condition for a full optimum. Marginal benefit of an additional unit of the
public good is the benefit people get one, plus the benefit of the person to
get, etc. Conversely, an additional unit of good given to the private sector or
one given to people 2.
The solution can be illustrated diagram enemies
cases where there are two people and two goods (X = private good, G = pure
public good). Figure 16-2 shows at the top of the indifference curve for the
citizens first and AB production constraints. Suppose we fix the UI of my
constituents in the indifference curve. II residents likely will be displayed
at the bottom of Fig. 16-2 by the CD (which differ between AB and UI). Clearly,
Pareto efficiency requires the marginal rate of substitution equals the slope
of the second individual CD curve (ie, at the point E). but this is only the
difference between the marginal rate of transformation (the slope of the
production possibilities schedule) and the individual's marginal rate of
substitution of the first (the slope of his indifference curve). Thus, we have
the MRT-MRS3.Pembiayaan Public Goods by Distortinary Taxation
If
government spending is financed by taxes that result in overload, it seems most
likely on the rules intuitively equate groundsthat ΣMRS the MRT will lead to
too high a level of expenditure. As given by Pigou,
That raised an additional £ incomes cause direct
harm to taxpayers as a body over and above the losses they suffered in the
actual payment. Where there is indirect, it should be added to the direct loss
of satisfaction involved in the withdrawal of the marginal unit of resources by
taxation, before this is balanced versus satisfaction generated by the marginal
expenditure.
3.OPTIMUM SUPPLY PURE
PUBLIC GOODS DISTRIBUTION
In this section we examine how the conditions for
the provision of public goods is influenced by considerations of optimal
distribution, paying particular attention to the situation where there are
restrictions on the set of feasible tax.
Redistribution and Non-distortion PerpajakanPada
previous section we derived the best fir allocation rules ΣMRS = MRT, where b
is the optimal use of lump-sum taxes and transfers. Normally, the government
does not enjoy complete freedom in the choice of a lump-sum tax, and indeed we
have previously found that this can be restricted uniform poll tax or subsidy.
Where it is, the ΣMRS = MRT condition ia no longer necessarily apply. To see
this, let us assume that the government can levy taxes Th household h, where Mh
is income (fixed). There is a good oneprivate (quantity h = Mh-Th) and a public
good (G). government chooses G and X to maximize.
Komentar
Posting Komentar